.

.
Library of Professor Richard A. Macksey in Baltimore

POSTS BY SUBJECT

Labels

Tuesday, April 13, 2010

The Federal Reserve-Then & Now (2)

The Federal Reserve: 
Then and Now 
Roger W. Garrison
Roger W. Garrison is associate professor of economics at Auburn University. 
He wishes to thank James Barth, Jeffrey Friedman, and Sven Thommesen for 
their helpful comments on an earlier version of this paper. 
The Review ofAustrian Economics Vo1.8, No. 1(1994): 3-19 
ISSN 0889-3047

PART 2

TheArtificial Boom

Textbook treatments of fiscal and monetary policy recognize that 
the fiscal authority and the Federal Reserve can work together. 
The Treasury issues debt and the Federal Reserve monetizes it. 
So long as government borrowing has not been pushed to irre- 
sponsible levels, debt issue and monetization have short-run 
effects on output and incomes that reinforce one another and 
short-run effects on the interest rate that cancel one another. 
These effects of policy are derived straightforwardly from stand- 
ard analysis which focuses on aggregate supply and aggregate 
demand. But when borrowing becomes excessive, considerations 
of risk become dominant. Going beyond the circumscribed focus 
of the textbook, we can recognize that the Treasury creates risk 
and the Federal Reserve externalizes it. 
To say that the Federal Reserve keeps the default-risk pre- 
mium off Treasury bills is not to say that the risk is actually 
eliminated. The burden of bearing it is simply shifted from the 
holders of Treasury securities to others. Borrowing and investing 
in the private sector becomes more risky than it otherwise would 
be. Holders of private debt and equity shares must concern 
themselves not only with all the usual risks and uncertainties of 
the marketplace but also with the risks and uncertainties attrib- 
utable to changes in the way the federal deficit is accommodated. 
Selling Treasury bills in foreign credit markets, in domestic credit 
markets, or to the Federal Reserve can have major effects on the 
strength of export markets, on domestic interest rates, and on the 
inflation rate. The inability of market participants to anticipate 
the Treasury's borrowing strategy translates into unanticipated 
changes in the value of private securities. 
If the additional risks attributed to federal budget deficits 
and imposed upon the private sector were allocated in some 
economically efficient way, there would have been no artificial 
boom arising from the irresponsible fiscal policy of the 1980s. The 
willingness to lend and to buy equity shares in the private sector 
would have been generally reduced, as wealth holders opted for 
the artificial security provided by government debt; but the re- 
duction in private-sector activity would have been minimized so 
long as the additional risks were assumed by those most willing 
to do so. This result, though, was precluded by institutional 
factors that hid the private-sector riskiness from those who were 
(unknowingly) financing risky undertakings. Again, the Federal 
Reserve plays a strong supporting role, as does the FDIC. To- 
gether, they enabled commercial banks and their depositors to 
finance risky ventures throughout the 1980s while being shielded 
either permanently or temporarily from the risks. This shield 
from risk bearing, like the low rate of interest in the 1920s, gave 
rise to an artificial boom and subsequent bust. 
The Depository Institutions Deregulation and Monetary 
Control Act of 1980 (DIDMCA) dramatically changed the bank- 
ing industry's ability and willingness to finance risky under- 
takings. Increased competition from nonbank financial institu- 
tions drove commercial banks to alter their lending policy so as 
to accept greater risks in order to achieve higher yields. The 
Federal Reserve in its long-established capacity of lender of last 
resort diminished the banks' concerns about possible problems 
of illiquidity while the FDIC absolved the banks' depositors of 
all worries about illiquidity and even about bankruptcy. Riskier 
loans, then, were only partially reflected in higher borrowing 
costs and lower share prices. In substantial measure, specific 
private-sector risks were transformed by DIDMCA, the Federal 
Reserve, and the FDIC into (1)the generalized risk of inflation 
in the event of excessive last-resort lending by the Federal Re- 
serve and (2) the risk of a large and unbudgeted liability in the 
event of excessive last-resort closings by the FDIC. Thus, economic 
activity in the private sector was spurred on by the lure of higher 
yields, yet it was largely unattenuated by considerations of 
risk, which were effectively externalized and diffused. 
The artificially low risk premiums stemming from the risk- 
externalizing effect of potential debt monetization in the 1980s 
paralleled the artificially low interest rates created by actual 
monetary expansion in the 1920s. What was without an earlier 
parallel, however, was the impact of deposit insurance in the 
post -warperiod. Throughout the 1980s, the FDIC continued 
to protect depositors while charging the banks a premium that 
was too low in general and, more significantly, that was unrelated 
to the riskiness of bank assets. This subsidy to risk-taking may 
have been significant enough, by itself, to create an artificial 
boom. There was no difficulty in finding risks to take. Banks could 
simply lend more heavily to overextended farmers, third-world 
countries, oil prospectors, and real estate developers; or they 
could find new risks such as those created by leveraged buyouts 
and the dramatic growth of the junk-bond market. It was the 
financial sector's demand for high-risk, high-yield securities, in 
fact, that gave junk bonds and other highly leveraged securities 
their buoyancy. 
Although it is possible to think of the FDIC as having its own 
independent effect throughout the 1980s, FDIC policy was actu- 
ally an integral part of the -fiscal, monetary, and regulatory 
environment that created and externalized risks. The Treasury 
created risk; the Federal Reserve and the FDIC externalized it. 
After all, speculative lending such as for commercial real estate 
development or for highly leveraged financial re-organizations 
are risky in large part because of possible changes in such things 
as the inflation rate, interest rate, trade flows, and tax rates-the 
very things that can undergo substantial and unpredictable 
change when the federal budget is dramatically out of balance. 
The 1980s may best be understood, then, as a decade in which the 
, policy-induced externalization of risk gave rise to a substantial 
but ultimately unsustainable economic boom. 

The Bust 

Potential debt monetization can keep Treasury bills risk free for 
the indefinite future; the reimbursement of depositors of failed 
banks can continue so long as the FDIC can be recapitalized out 
of general tax revenues. But the banking industry cannot be 
shielded from the consequences of excessive risk-taking forever. 
For almost a decade the banking industry and the speculative 
activities it supported were able to keep the economic expansion 
going. Although risk aversion normally characterizes sound 
banking, high-flying banks in the 1980s were able to indulge in 
risky lending despite the preferences of their depositors and to 
escape both market-imposed or government-imposed discipline 
until the cumulative effects of externalizing risk turned the 
undue risk-taking into a financial crisis. The Federal Reserve's 
routine functioning as lender of last resort, the FDIC's de facto 
policy of forbearance in cases of problem banks, and the implicit 
acceptance of the doctrine of "too big to fail," all help to account 
for the length of the artificial boom. But neither increased last- 
resort lending and forbearing nor more overt inflationary finance, 
such as was pursued in the 1920s, could keep the boom going 
indefinitely. As with the artificial boom in the interwar period, an 
eventual bust was inevitable. 
Like the time-consuming production processes that were 
out of line with time preferences, speculative loan portfolios 
that were out of line with risk preferences generated an artifi- 
cial boom in the 1980s that belonged to the same general class 
as that of the 1920s. However, the distinction between eco- 
nomic activities that are excessively future-oriented and eco- 
nomic activities that are excessively speculative-together with 
some institutional considerations-allows us to see systematic 
differences between the 1930s and the 1990s. 
First, the downturn at the end of the Bullish Eighties came 
in the form of a bank-led bust. A high rate of bank failures was 
experienced well before the general economic contraction. At the 
end of the Roaring Twenties, by contrast, the bank failures came 
after the economic contraction had begun. This difference in the 
timing of events is consistent with differences in the nature of 
the two expansions. Industrial borrowers in the 1920s were 
using newly created funds for excessively capital-intensive 
ventures that, in general, were not otherwise excessively 
speculative. It is true, of course, that there was heavy specula- 
tion in securities markets in the 1920s-much more so then than 
in the 1980s-but the cause-and-effect relationship in the recent 
episode was the reverse of that in the earlier one. That is, in the 
19209, monetary expansion, which allowed banks to support 
heavy industry, also fueled speculation in securities markets. 
However, because the risks of that speculation were born, in the 
first instance, by the buyers of the securities, there was no 
policy-induced externalization of risk to weaken banks even as 
the expansion continued. In the 1980s, policy-induced specula- 
tion, on the part of the banks themselves and their industrial 
borrowers, eroded bank capital, weakening the banks throughout 
the boom-so much so that the erosion of their capital base 
eventually turned boom into bust. 
Second, while the idleness of plant, equipment, labor, and 
other resources that characterized the 1930s has its counterpart 
in the semi-idleness in the 1990s, the disposition of unprofitable 
assets is different now, largely because the recent bust was 
bank-led. During the Great Depression, firms whose revenues did 
not cover operating costs simply closed their doors. Work on 
incomplete industrial projects whose present value had turned 
negative was simply discontinued. Although this form of market 
discipline was sometimes delayed by policies aimed at rekindling 
the boom, eventually resource idleness characterized those sec- 
tors of the economy that were most out of line with underlying 
economic realities, and liquidation could proceed apace. In the 
current slowdown, many failing firms are first identified as non- 
performing loans in the portfolios of failed banks. As insolvent 
banks are closed by the FDIC, the bad loans are transferred to 
the Resolution Trust Corporation (RTC), which functions as a 
caretaker until it can sell the assets. In many cases, the physi- 
cal assets, such as franchised motels or restaurants, are not 
idled. Instead, the RTC contracts with an operating company 
to run the business. The contract allows the operating company 
to earn a profit while minimizing the cost to the RTC of main- 
taining the assets. 
The existence of many such failed-but-still-operating busi- 
nesses, including firms undergoing bankruptcy proceedings but 
still operating with the newly evolved debtor-in-possession (DIP) 
financing, helps to explain why the current recession is a rela- 
tively shallow one by conventional measures. What otherwise 
would be idle capital is partially masked by RTC policy as under- 
employed capital-analogous to the underemployed labor associ- 
ated with 1930s-style make-work projects. "Zombie banks," banks 
that are allowed to continue operations after their net worth has 
turned negative, have their counterpart in RTC-owned or DIP-fi- 
nanced "zombie firms."" While the underemployed capital in zombie firms limited the 
depth of the recession, it added to the length. Recovery consists 
of re-employing resources idled by the bust. As confirmed by 
loon the role of government in adding to the severity of the Great Depression 
and,delaying recovery, see Gene Smiley, "Can Keynesianism Explain the 1930s?: 
Reply to Cowen," Critical Review 5, no. 1(Winter 1991): 81-114 and Richard K. 
Vedder and Lowell E. Gallaway, Out of Work (New York: Holmes and Meier, 1993), 
pp. 74-149. 'The term "zombie S&Lsn was coined by Edward J. Kane in the context of the 
savings-and-loan crisis, which was a precursor to the crisis in the banking industry 
and subsequent recession. See Edward J.Kane, "Dangers of Capital Forbearance: 
The Case of the FSLIC and the 'Zombie' S&Ls," Contemporary Policy Issues 5, no. 
1 (January 1987): 77-83. For a healthy perspective on RTC policy and DIP 
financing, see Stephen Delos Wilson, The Bankruptcy of America (Germantown, 
Tenn.: Ridge Mills Press, 19921, pp. 81-96 andpassim. 
experience in the early 1990s, it would have been easier to draw 
resources out of idleness than to draw them away from the RTC. 
Asset managers of the RTC, trying to avoid spoiling markets 
that dumping real assets at fire-sale price would entail, stock- 
piled them instead, creating a huge "overhang" which added 
significantly to the uncertainties in the private sector. Also, 
solvent firms and would-be upstarts, who would have to raise 
their own capital to expand or enter the market, are not eager to 
compete with bankrupt firms or with privately operated but 
RTC-owned businesses whose revenues do not have to cover the 
costs of capital. Considerations of these sorts help to explain why 
the government's recent recourse to monetary stimulation in the 
form of exceedingly low discount rates has met with such little 
success. 
Third, the unemployment currently being experienced has a 
distinctly different composition from that of the 1930s. It is 
widely reported that white-collar workers are disproportionately 
affected in the current recession as compared to earlier cyclical 
downturns. The time-preferencelrisk-preference frame of analy- 
sis makes this composition difference readily understandable. 
The boom in the 1920s involved resources allocated dispropor- 
tionately to capital-intensive projects, such as steel mills and 
manufacturing plants. The labor complement to heavy industry 
tends to be predominantly blue-collar. The boom in the 1980s 
involved resources allocated to speculative development, such as 
commercial real estate and financial services. The labor comple- 
ment to this kind of capital tends to be predominantly white-col- 
lar. In both episodes, the composition of unemployment matches 
the pattern of capital misallocation. 
Finally, macroeconomic policy after the bust reveals a critical 
difference between the current situation and that of the 1930s. 
When further monetary expansion, which sustained the boom of 
the 1920s for nearly a decade, could sustain it no longer, both the 
monetary expansion and the boom came to an end. The public's 
increased demand for currency relative to checking-account 
money, coupled with the increased reluctance on the part of 
commercial banks to lend, swamped the Federal Reserve's efforts 
to re-inflate.12 Despite the further padding of the monetary base, 
the dynamic of the bust itself was an effective check against 
continued monetary expansion. By contrast, when further deficit 
spending and risk externalization, which sustained the boom of 
''see Smiley, "Can Keynesianism Explain the 1930s?" p. 88. 
the 1980s, could sustain it no longer, the boom ended, but the 
deficit spending and risk externalization escalated. In fact, de- 
creased tax revenues and increased payments of entitlements, 
both associated with recession, led to still more government 
borrowing. The dynamic of the bust, then, provided increased 
scope for the very kind of irresponsible fiscal policy that made the 
bust inevitable.

How Little "We" Know

The failure at the dawn of the last decade to extend deregulation 
to the provision of deposit insurance and the absence of any 
market check against the Treasury's fiscal excesses provide dra- 
matic illustration of the general fallacy of the mixed economy. 
Privatized profit seeking coupled with socialized risk bearing 
undergirded both the bull market of the 1980s and the harsher 
economic realities of the 1990s. The risks assumed by lenders and 
borrowers, savers and investors, hedgers and leveragers are ren- 
dered inconsistent with the actual risk preferences of wealth 
holders in the marketplace by the FDIC subsidy to risk bearing 
and by the Fed-backed Treasury, whose power to issue risk-free 
debt imposes risks on the private sector. 
Researchers at the Federal Reserve are just two steps away 
from recognizing the problem of deficit-induced uncertainties 
as evidenced by a recent article entitled "How Little We Know 
About Deficit Policy ~ffects."'~ Macroeconomic data as illumi- 
nated by several sophisticated modeling and econometric tech- 
niques have led two economists at the Minneapolis Federal Re- 
serve Bank to conclude with confidence that "Deficit policies may 
matter, and then again they may not. Existing studies really don't 
tell us much about their effects."14 The first step from this 
disturbingly limp conclusion to a healthy understanding of the 
deficit problem is to recognize that the "We" in the title of the 
article, intended to mean "We Economists," can be extended to 
mean "We Lenders-Borrowers-Savers-Investors-Hedgers-Lever- 
agers" or simply "We Market Participants." Market participants 
do not know how deficit accommodation will affect future market 
conditions, so they have to make guesses. And if they guess 
131'reston J. Miller and William Roberds, "How Little We Know About Deficit 
Policy Effects," The Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 16, no. 1 
(Winter 1992): 1-12. 141bid.,p. 8'''  wrong, they may lose big. The second step is to recognize that the "We" may also refer to the holders of Treasury securities. Accord- 
ingly, the title phrase should be amended to read "How Little We 
Know or Care about Deficit Policy Effects." The potential for debt 
monetization, as manifested by the Federal Reserve in its stand- 
by capacity, has absolved the Treasury's creditors of any inclina- 
tion to care. Externalizing risk has precluded any possibility that 
the reluctance of creditors will provide an effective check against 
the excesses of the Treasury. The tripling of federal government indebtedness since the 
beginning of the 1980s' bull market stands as testimony to the 
capacity of the Treasury to issue its artificially risk-free debt. The 
banking legislation of 1980 has shown us its capacity for blinding 
the banking industry and the private sector to the black cloud of 
debt gathering above it. Together, the actions of the fiscal and 
monetary authorities have demonstrated once again how public 
institutions ostensibly devoted to stability and prosperity are, in 
the end, responsible for crises and decay. 

No comments:

Post a Comment